All assets are illiquid |
Date: Thursday, December 23, 2010
Author: Aswath Damodaran, HedgeTracker
Much of financial theory is built on the premise that markets are liquid for the
most part and that illiquidity, if it exists, occurs in pockets: it shows up
only with very small, lightly traded companies, emerging markets and privately
owned businesses. In fact, almost the prescriptions we provide to both investors
and corporate finance reflect this trust that both security and asset markets
are liquid.
To see how unrealistic the assumption of liquidity is, consider what a liquid
market would require: you should be instantaneously be able to sell
any quantity of an asset at the prevailing market price with no
transactions costs. Using that definition, no asset is liquid and the only
question then becomes one of degree, with some assets being more liquid than
others.
Given the premise that all assets are illiquid, here is a follow up
question: how do you measure illiquidity? One obvious measure, especially in
securities markets, is the total transactions costs, including not only
the brokerage costs, but the bid-ask spread and the price impact from trading.
The other is waiting time. In real estate, for instance, illiquidity
manifests itself in properties staying on the market for longer periods. Days on
market (DOM) is a widely reported statistic in real estate and is used to
measure the health (and liquidity) of different markets.
There is significant empirical evidence that illiquidity varies across asset
classes, within assets in a given asset class and across time.
• Across asset classes, illiquidity is more of a problem in real asset markets
(real estate, collectibles) than in financial asset markets. Within financial
asset markets, the US treasury market is the most liquid, followed by highly
rated bonds and developed market stocks, with low-rated (junk or high yield)
bonds and emerging market stocks bringing up the rear.
• Within each asset class, there are wide variations in liquidity. In the
treasury market, the just-issued, standard maturity treasuries (3 month, 6
month, 10 year) are more liquid than the seasoned, non-standard maturity
treasuries. Within the stock market, larger market cap and higher priced stocks
are more liquid than smaller market cap, lower priced stocks.
• Liquidity also varies widely over time. While the long term trend in liquidity
in equity markets has been towards more liquidity, liquidity moves in cycles,
increasing in bull markets and decreasing in bear markets. Punctuating the long
term trend are crises, like the 1987 sell-off in the US and the 2008 banking
crisis, where liquidity dries up even for the largest market cap companies.
During these crises, illiquidity manifests itself in many ways: trading halts,
higher bid-ask spreads and bigger price impact when trading.
None of this evidence would matter if investors did not care about
illiquidity but there is clear evidence that they do: liquid treasuries have
lower yields (and higher prices) than illiquid treasuries and investors demand
higher returns on stocks with lower trading volume and higher bid-ask spreads.
One study find that every 1% increase in bid-ask spreads increased expected
returns by 0.25%, and these higher required returns push down asset prices.
Adding to the problem, the price that investors charge for illiquidity also
varies over time, spiking during periods of crises: illiquid assets get
discounted even more during these periods.
If illiquidity varies across asset classes, across assets and across time, and
investors price in this illiquidity, it seems prudent that both portfolio and
corporate financial theory be modified to reflect the potential for illiquidity.
Alas, given the length of this post, that has to wait for the next one.
Reproduction in whole or in part without permission is prohibited.